perm filename IBM.ESS[ESS,JMC] blob
sn#151919 filedate 1975-03-26 generic text, type C, neo UTF8
COMMENT ā VALID 00002 PAGES
C REC PAGE DESCRIPTION
C00001 00001
C00002 00002 THE IBM ANTI-TRUST CASE AND THE PUBLIC INTEREST
C00017 ENDMK
Cā;
THE IBM ANTI-TRUST CASE AND THE PUBLIC INTEREST
The Justice Department started a few years ago a new
anti-trust case against IBM. In addition, CDC, various software
companies, various companies making peripheral equipment, and various
leasing companies have also filed suit. The purpose of this essay is
to try to determine what the interests of the the various parties are
in the matter and especially what should be the stand of the computer
scientists.
We may consider that the public has the following interests:
1. It wants good computers at reasonable prices.
2. It wants a wide variety of choice in computers, peripheral
equipment and software.
3. It wants the technology to develop rapidly and for new
ideas to be encouraged and tested.
IBM has the following interests, and I will not presume to
speculate on their relative importance:
1. Its stockholders want the stock to go up.
2. Its executives, and engineers and scientists want to do a
good professional job in providing computers.
3. Its salesmen want to beat the competition and exceed their
quotas.
4. Its executives want to lead a peaceful life and avoid
harassment and lawsuits.
5. All its people would like to keep it intact as an
organization, because to do otherwise would make life very uncertain.
IBM's competitors have the following interests:
1. Survival as organizations. For some of them, this is not
a serious question, but others have gone broke for various reasons.
Even if IBM is not directly involved in a debacle, there is often a
possibility of survival by pressing IBM on monopoly grounds. In one
case, a few years ago, it seemed to me that a company that didn't
deserve to survive succeeded in blackmailing IBM into giving it money
and agreeing not to compete with it in a certain market.
2. Profits.
3. Assured markets.
4. Doing a good job.
The Justice Department has the following interests:
1. Their conception of what the public interest is. Breaking
up a company with 70 percent of the business in an industry is
certainly the obvious solution, but there are drawbacks. The first
is that when elephants fight, the mice get stomped. If IBM and its
resources were divided into three or four parts and competed freely,
each part might be so strong that the non-IBM computer companies
would be wiped out.
2. Individually, the Justice Department lawyers would like to
make their reputations by winning the big case.
In my opinion, the following additional considerations need
to be taken into account:
1. The present situation is not intolerable. IBM's fraction
of the market has been stable since the computer business started in
the early 1950's. Its competitors have prospered when they made
better computers than IBM in some market and have declined when they
have made worse. The same is true of the peripheral equipment
manufacturers, the software companies and the leasing companies. On
the other hand, perhaps the situation can be improved by some kind of
anti-monopoly action. We shall come to that.
2. The interests of the competitors are not identical with
the interests of the public. If present trends continue, the result
may be the creation of a cartel, i.e. an agreed division of the
various markets, created and maintained by the U.S. government under
the illusion that it is promoting competition. A prize example of
the creation of a cartel is the recent settlement between IBM and CDC
wherein IBM agreed to give CDC its service bureau subsidiary and not
to compete in that business any more in exchange for CDC calling off
its anti-trust suit. IBM had much less than half the service bureau
business, so that this agreement probably reduced competition in that
business. As such, some of the other companies attacked the
agreement, but it may be that each of them will be satisfied if it
gets its cut. Certainly, the fears of going out of business of many
companies would be alleviated by an agreed market division.
In my opinion, this would be very bad for the country.
Philco and General Electric and RCA and a number of smaller losers in
the computer business deserved to go out of the computer business in
the sense that they made no product not bettter made by someone else.
Once a cartel has been created, any company about to go under will be
able to demand a redistribution of the business. This will be at the
expense of the users of computers.
Another proposal by one of the competitors was that IBM be
broken up according to product lines, e.g. into a 145 company etc.
(This was their example). The effect of this would be to preserve a
division of computers by size that is probably already obsolete. It
would also be a legal nightmare to determine what is a legitimate
successor of a 145 in a different technology.
3. The public has suffered from the dominance of IBM in the
following ways only some of which may be remediable by the courts:
a. IBM has built less than optimal computers and their losing
features have been copied by the competition. Here are some
examples: For many years, no-one built computers that addressed more
than 32K words, because IBM was building successors to its successful
704. No company except D.E.C. with the PDP-10 has really made the
full transition to time-sharing computer systems. No-one had to,
because IBM goofed when they came out with the 360 as they have
recently realized and admitted.
It is not clear whether an altered structure of the computer
industry would help. It may merely a plea that computer engineers be
smarter and see further ahead.
b. IBM's secrecy certainly works to the disadvantage of
progress in the computer field. Because, almost no-one outside the
company knows what they are doing, there is no criticism if they are
hatching a large egg for the public that will appear in five years.
The lack of time-sharing for the 360 is a case in point, and I have
reason to fear they will lay another suboptimal egg in a few years.
IBM's excuse for this secrecy is the anti-trust consent
decree of 1965 which forbids them to hint at new products before they
are ready to quote price, performance and delivery. Certainly, the
Justice Department has always allowed them to maintain this position.
However, IBM has a tradition of secrecy dating to long before the
consent decree, and the secrecy has been applied in areas far from
new products. Moreover, even in the area of new products, the
secrecy is mainly to the disadvantage of competition. This is a case
where lack of technical knowledge by the Justice Department and the
courts led to results which were opposed to what they were trying to
promote. Let me illustrate these assertions.
First, IBM's tradition of secrecy. One retired IBM scientist
told me that when he started at IBM in 1949, each senior engineer at
Endicott locked up his laboratory at night, and the laboratory didn't
open until he unlocked it in the morning. At that time, IBM's
business was in electro-mechanical devices with a long development
time, i.e. inventions in the classical sense, and this has always
been the fortress of industrial secrecy. IBM became gradually less
secretive until the early 1960's and then got worse again. At least,
this is my personal impression as an occasional IBM consultant.
Second, two examples of the secrecy going far beyond new
products. Both of these are based on personal experience. In 1962,
I published a method for defining the semantics of computer
languages, and an IBM laboratory took up this method, improved it,
and used it to describe the semantics of IBM's new language PL/I.
Because of personal contacts and because I was an IBM consultant, I
was aware of this, and when a big report was ready after several
years I received a copy of it as an IBM Confidential document. After
considerable protest on my part, they "declassified" the reports and
the work has been public since. Everyone concerned agreed that the
work was of a general scientific character and revealing it in no way
pre-announced a product. Such was the atmosphere of secrecy,
however, that it required the protest of an outsider accidentally
aware of it, to get it released.
A second example is the manual for a version of the LISP
programming language that IBM Research prepared on the basis of a
version of LISP for the IBM 360 developed at Stanford University. It
was also declared condidential, and, so far as I know, was never
released.
I don't know what other purely scientific treasures IBM may
be hiding, more through inadvertence than policy.
However, the major disadvantage of IBM's secrecy to the
public is its effect on competition and progress in the computer
industry. Perhaps we should put it another way. Namely, here are
some major advantages to making IBM modify its secrecy policy: